Economics Chapter 11 Homework Although the textbook does not spend a lot of time on the

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 9
subject Words 5513
subject Authors N. Gregory Mankiw

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
page-pf1
255
CHAPTER 11
Aggregate Demand I: Building the
IS-LM Model
Notes to the Instructor
Chapter Summary
Comments
Presentation of ISLM is greatly facilitated by the fact that students have seen all of the elements
already. This makes it much easier to teach than when it is taught prior to a long-run model. The
amount of time spent on the material in Chapters 11 and 12 is partly a matter of taste. It probably
requires three lectures at a minimum to present basic ISLM (omitting detailed discussion of the
Great Depression from Chapter 12), although some instructors might prefer to spend up to six
lectures on this material.
When teaching the IS curve some instructors may find that it is preferable to start with the
loanable-funds derivation of the IS curve. The advantage of this approach is that it builds on the
Chapter 3 model: Equilibrium in Chapter 3 is summarized by 𝑆𝑌=𝐼(𝑟), where 𝑌 is
exogenous; the IS curve is simply given by S(Y) = I(r), where income is now an endogenous
variable. The Keynesian cross can then be presented as a special case.
Use of the Web Site
The model exercises for Chapter 3 can be used as an alternative way to derive the IS curve.
Students can calculate and graph all of the {r, Y} pairs consistent with goods-market equilibrium
Use of the Dismal Scientist Web Site
Use the Dismal Scientist Web site to download annual data for the U.S. consumer price index
and the 1-year and 10-year Treasury yields over the last 20 years. Compute the real interest rate
for each of the Treasury yields by subtracting CPI inflation from each yield. Discuss how real
interest rates change with inflation in the short run compared to what you would expect over
longer periods of time.
page-pf2
256 | CHAPTER 11 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS-LM Model
Chapter Supplements
This chapter includes the following supplements:
11-2 Mr. Keynes and the Classics: The Art of Modeling
11-4 Additional Readings
page-pf3
Lecture Notes | 257
Lecture Notes
Introduction
We now have a basic idea of how the economy functions in the short run. Because in the short
run prices are not completely flexible, changes in aggregate demand affect output, not just
prices. To develop this short-run theory of the economy, we must now consider aggregate
demand and supply in more detail. This chapter and the next present a more detailed analysis of
11-1 The Goods Market and the IS Curve
The building blocks of the ISLM model are familiar from earlier analysis. The IS side of the
model summarizes equilibrium in the goods market and is based partly on the classical model of
Chapter 3; the LM side of the model summarizes equilibrium in the money market and so is
related to the analysis of money in Chapter 5.
The basic equation summarizing equilibrium in the goods market, for a closed economy, is
familiar:
Y = C + I + G.
As before, we suppose that
C = C(Y T)
I = I(r)
𝐺=!𝐺
𝑇=!𝑇.
The only difference from our earlier analysis is that we no longer suppose that real GDP is
determined on the supply side, since that is true only in the long run. But this is far from an
innocuous change. Previously, given that Y was fixed at Y, we were able to use this model to
determine the equilibrium interest rate in the economy. Now, there are different combinations of
the interest rate and the level of GDP that are consistent with equilibrium. Writing equilibrium in
terms of the loans market gives
S(Y) = I(r).
Recall from the analysis of the classical model that
So an increase in income increases total saving, other things being equal. We know, therefore,
that it decreases the interest rate. Thus, we draw the conclusion that, for equilibrium to exist in
the goods market, higher levels of GDP must be associated with lower interest rates.
We can tell the same story another way. Suppose that interest rates increase. This
decreases the level of investment. In response to this fall in investment demand, firms produce
less output. Now recall the circular flow. A decrease in output leads firms to employ fewer
page-pf4
258 | CHAPTER 11 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS-LM Model
workers and to use their capital less intensively; hence, income goes down. In response to the
decreased income, households consume less. This effect on consumption reinforces the initial
effect, so we get the same conclusionhigher interest rates are associated with lower output,
and vice versa.
The Keynesian Cross
A common means of deriving the IS curve, based on the second explanation above, is known as
the Keynesian cross. The Keynesian cross also gives us insights into how fiscal policy affects
the economy. The key idea of this model is that planned expenditure may differ from actual
expenditure if firms sell less or more than they anticipated and so build up or run down their
inventory. Planned expenditure is simply the amount that households, firms, and the government
intend to spend on goods and services. We write it as
Planned expenditure is thus an increasing function of income.
In equilibrium, planned expenditure equals actual expenditure, which, of course, equals
GDP
PE = Y.
We can graph both planned and actual expenditure against income to get the Keynesian cross
diagram.
The adjustment to equilibrium takes the form of changes in inventory. If actual
expenditure exceeds planned expenditure, this means that firms produced too much. Remember
that inventory investment is counted as expenditure; it is as if firms sell the goods to themselves.
Actual expenditure exceeds planned expenditure when firms accumulate inventory. In this
circumstance, firms would cut back on their production, lessening their inventory accumulation
and so decreasing actual expenditure. An analogous situation occurs if planned expenditure
exceeds actual expenditure. In this case, firms are unintentionally getting rid of inventory, giving
them an incentive to increase production. In practice, we think that this adjustment takes place
rapidly, so we focus upon the situation where the economy is in equilibrium.
What happens if planned spending increases? For example, suppose that government
spending increases. That would induce firms to produce more output. Recalling the circular
flow, this implies that workers and owners of firms obtain more income and so increase their
consumption. Planned spending and, ultimately, output go up by more than the original increase
in government spending. To put it another way, government spending has a multiplier effect on
output through the government-purchases multiplier.
What is the economics behind this process? The answer can be found in the circular flow
!Figure 11-3
!Figure 11-4
!Figure 11-5
page-pf5
Lecture Notes | 259
Y/G = 1/(1 MPC).
The multiplier has a couple of interpretationsone benign, the other less so. From one
perspective, we can think about the multiplier as telling us that we have the power to use fiscal
policy to affect the economy dramatically in the short run. This suggests that fiscal policy might
be a potent tool for stimulating the economy in a recession, for example. But another implication
Case Study: Cutting Taxes to Stimulate the Economy:
The Kennedy and Bush Tax Cuts
Cuts in personal and corporate income taxes were used by President Kennedy to stimulate the
economy in 1964 on the advice of his Council of Economic Advisers. The economy grew
rapidly in the wake of these cuts. Keynesian economists think that this experience supports the
idea, embodied in the Keynesian cross model, that tax cuts stimulate aggregate demand and
boost the economy. Tax cuts may also increase people’s incentive to supply labor, thus
increasing the aggregate supply of goods and services.
Case Study: Increasing Government Purchases to Stimulate the
Economy: The Obama Stimulus
President Obama’s stimulus plan for the economy was passed by Congress and signed into law
in February 2009. The plan, which totaled nearly $800 billion in spending and tax cuts,
represented a classic Keynesian-style response to the worsening recession. Economists debated
the plan, in particular the relatively heavier emphasis on spending as opposed to tax reductions.
In justifying the plan’s larger spending component, Obama administration economists argued
that the multiplier for government purchases was about 50 percent greater than the multiplier for
page-pf6
260 | CHAPTER 11 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS-LM Model
Case Study: Using Regional Data to Estimate Multipliers
Keynesian theory suggests that changes in taxes and government spending have important
effects on income and output for the economy. But in practice, measuring the effects on the
economy from fiscal policy is difficult because there is no simple way to control for other events
that are also affecting the economy. For example, fiscal stimulus is often adopted in response to
a weak economy, so it is difficult to separate the effects of stimulus from the effects of
prolonged fallout from a recession. Recent studies have attempted to address this problem by
using data from states or provinces within a country. Some regional variation in government
spending is unrelated to other events affecting regional economies, allowing the economic
The Interest Rate, Investment, and the IS Curve
The transition from the Keynesian cross model to the IS curve is achieved by noting that planned
investment changes if the real interest rate changes. The Keynesian cross analysis tells us that
changes in planned investment change GDP. For example, if interest rates increase, planned
investment falls, and so does output. Thus, higher levels of the interest rate are associated with
lower levels of output.
How Fiscal Policy Shifts the IS Curve
The position of the IS curve depends on fiscal-policy variables. Increases in government
spending or decreases in taxes increase the equilibrium level of output at any given interest rate.
Thus they are associated with outward shifts in the IS curve.
11-2 The Money Market and the LM Curve
The Theory of Liquidity Preference
To understand the determination of interest rates, we turn to the money market. Again, our
building blocks are familiar from the classical model. Our starting point is the condition for
equilibrium in the money market:
M/P = L(i, Y).
!Figure 11-7
!Figure 11-8
page-pf7
Lecture Notes | 261
M/P = L(r, Y).
We reintroduce expected inflation in Chapter 11.
Just as the IS curve gives us {r, Y} combinations consistent with equilibrium in the goods
market, the LM curve gives us {r, Y} combinations consistent with equilibrium in the money
market. To see how this works, consider a diagram of the market for money. Notice that the
demand for money depends on r and Y. Increases in r decrease the demand for money; increases
in Y increase the demand for money. The supply of and demand for money determine the
equilibrium interest rate. Note also that changes in the money supply therefore affect the
equilibrium interest rate.
Case Study: Does a Monetary Tightening Raise or Lower
Interest Rates?
In the early 1980s, Paul Volcker, the chairman of the Federal Reserve, slowed the rate of money
growth in a successful attempt to decrease inflation. The Fisher equation teaches us that lower
Income, Money Demand, and the LM Curve
The basic analysis of the LM curve is now straightforward. Higher GDP raises the demand for
money. If the real supply of money is fixed, then interest rates must rise to bring the demand for
money back in line with the supply. So higher GDP is associated with higher interest rates when
the money market is in equilibrium. The LM curve slopes upward.
How Monetary Policy Shifts the LM Curve
The position of the LM curve depends on the real money supply. An increase in the real money
supply for a given level of GDP implies lower interest rates. An increase in the money supply
thus shifts the LM curve downward and conversely.
11-3 Conclusion: The Short-Run Equilibrium
Finally, we can put the IS and LM curves together and find the one {r, Y} combination that is
consistent with equilibrium in both the goods and the money markets. Since points on the IS
!
Figure 11-9
!
Figure 11-10
!
Figure 11-11
!
Figure 11-12
!
Figure 11-13
!Figure 11-14
page-pf8
LECTURE SUPPLEMENT
11-1 The Key Features of the ISLM Model
The ISLM analysis is simply a more detailed look at what lies behind aggregate demand. It decomposes
1. The position of the LM curve depends on M/P.
3. Increases in the price level shift the LM curve in.
5. The position of the IS curve depends on G and T.
7. Exogenous spending shocks shift the IS curve.
9. Expansionary fiscal policy works by directly increasing spending but leads to short-run
10. Expansionary monetary policy works by pushing down interest rates and thus encouraging
investment spending.
11. The adjustment of the economy to long-run equilibrium operates through changes in the price
level, leading to changes in M/P, and hence in interest rates and investment. In the ISLM
page-pf9
263
ADDITIONAL CASE STUDY
11-2 Mr. Keynes and the Classics: The Art of Modeling
Keynesian economics was born with the publication of The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money, by John Maynard Keynes. In terms of its impact on the discipline, this was surely one of the most
important books in the history of economics. Yet for the modern student of economics, it makes for
difficult reading. Apparently, this was also true for contemporary readers: “It will be admitted by the least
what point the new investment-demand schedule will cut it. If, however, we introduce the state
of liquidity-preference and the quantity of money and these between them tell us that the rate
of interest is r2, then the whole position becomes determinate…. Thus the [investment] curve
and the [saving] curves tell us nothing about the rate of interest. They only tell us what income
will be, if from some other source we can say what the rate of interest is.2
Oxford University Press, 1967), 12642.
2 J.M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London: Macmillan, 1936), 181.
3 Hicks, Critical Essays in Monetary Theory, 135.
4 Hicks, Critical Essays in Monetary Theory, 135.
page-pfa
264
ADVANCED TOPIC
11-3 The ISLM Model: A Critical Evaluation
The ISLM model occupies a curious position in modern macroeconomics. It has been at the heart of much
macroeconomic theory and policy from its invention in 1936 to the present. Professional macroeconomists
in business, government, and academia utilize the model to help them understand the world. Yet, at the
same time, many professional economistsparticularly academicshave become increasingly skeptical
of its usefulness. Critics of ISLM argue that the model is flawed because it is inherently static, lacks
microeconomic underpinnings, and does not provide an adequate treatment of expectations. One such
critic, Robert King, concludes that “the ISLM model has no greater prospect of being a viable analytical
vehicle for macroeconomics in the 1990s than the Ford Pinto has of being a sporty, reliable car for the
1990s.”1
One way to introduce dynamics into an ISLM model is to make price adjustment endogenous. Much
Keynesian modeling in the 1960s and 1970s took this approach. The idea was to explain the adjustment of
wages and prices over time based on supply and demand in the labor and goods markets. For example, if
output is above its natural rate, then unemployment will be below its natural rate. Strong demand for
goods and labor would then cause wages and prices to rise. In this setting, the ISLM model explains
output at a point in time, given the price level, while the specification of price adjustment explains how
prices change, given past values of output. Such an approach will be successful only if we can adequately
capture the complexities of price and wage adjustment by simple, ad hoc price and wage equations. And
that, in turn, brings us back to the question of microeconomic underpinnings.
The search for solid microeconomic foundations for the ISLM model has been going on since the
early days of Keynesian economics. Researchers in the 1950s and 1960s provided microeconomic
justification for the consumption function, the investment function, and the money demand function that
are used in the ISLM model. (Much of this work is explained in Part V of the textbook.) More recently,
page-pfb
265
but raising nominal rates. Evidently, the conclusions that we draw are sensitive to our assumptions about
expectations, and the basic ISLM analysis will be correct only if the expectational effects are small.3
Given this deficiency of the ISLM model, why do so many still find it a helpful way to think about
the economy? The answer is, perhaps, that it still provides the easiest way to understand the determination
of aggregate demand and the transmission of monetary and fiscal policies in an economy characterized by
significant price stickiness. Unfortunately, macroeconomists have not yet derived simple and tractable
models that both provide a satisfactory treatment of expectations and take into account wage and price
page-pfc
LECTURE SUPPLEMENT
11-4 Additional Readings
John Maynard Keynes’s General Theory is a true classic of economics, although it is a difficult and often
confusing work. Some economists believe that Hicks’s ISLM model does not really do justice to
Keynes’s ideas, particularly with regard to Keynes’s views on expectations (see Chapter 12 of General
Theory) and wageprice adjustment (see Chapter 19 of General Theory). Readers who wish to make a

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.