Chapter 3 Homework The Opportunity Costs Are Constant The Production

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 12
subject Words 5754
subject Authors N. Gregory Mankiw

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
page-pf1
33
WHAT’S NEW IN THE SIXTH EDITION:
There are no major changes to this chapter.
LEARNING OBJECTIVES:
By the end of this chapter, students should understand:
how everyone can benefit when people trade with one another.
CONTEXT AND PURPOSE:
Chapter 3 is the third chapter in the three-chapter section that serves as the introduction of the text.
Chapter 1 introduced ten fundamental principles of economics. Chapter 2 developed how economists
approach problems. This chapter shows how people and countries gain from trade (which is one of the
KEY POINTS:
Each person consumes goods and services produced by many other people both in our country and
around the world. Interdependence and trade are desirable because they allow everyone to enjoy a
greater quantity and variety of goods and services.
3
INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE
GAINS FROM TRADE
page-pf2
34 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
CHAPTER OUTLINE:
I. A Parable for the Modern Economy
A. Example: two goodsmeat and potatoes; and two peoplea cattle rancher and a potato farmer
(each of whom likes to consume both potatoes and meat).
1. The gains from trade are obvious if the farmer can only grow potatoes and the rancher can
only raise cattle.
B. Production Possibilities
1. The farmer and rancher both work eight hours per day and can use this time to grow
potatoes, raise cattle, or both.
Make sure that you write out all of the algebra involved in this example. If you leave
out steps, students will not understand how these calculations are made.
Begin by explaining that there are two basic ways that individuals can satisfy their
wants. The first is to be economically self-sufficient. The second is to specialize in the
production of one thing and then trade with others. With rare exceptions, individuals
and nations tend to rely on specialization and trade. One way to demonstrate this is
to survey the students on their future plans (doctors, lawyers, teachers, etc.). Point
out that they plan to specialize and trade. Ask them why this is optimal.
page-pf3
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 35
Minutes Needed to
Make One Ounce of:
Meat
Potatoes
Meat
Potatoes
Farmer
60 min./oz.
15 min./oz.
8/1=8 oz.
8/0.25=32 oz.
Rancher
20 min./oz.
10 min./oz.
8/0.33=24 oz.
8/0.16=48 oz.
3. The production possibilities frontiers can also be drawn.
a. These production possibilities frontiers are drawn linearly instead of being bowed out.
This assumes that the farmer's and the rancher's technology for producing meat and
potatoes allows them to switch between producing one good and the other at a constant
rate.
4. We will assume that the farmer and rancher divide their time equally between raising cattle
and growing potatoes.
a. The farmer produces (and consumes) at point A16 ounces of potatoes and 4 ounces of
meat.
Figure 1
page-pf4
36 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
C. Specialization and Trade
1. Suppose the rancher suggests that the farmer specialize in the production of potatoes and
then trade with the rancher for meat.
a. The rancher will spend six hours a day producing meat (18 ounces) and two hours a
week growing potatoes (12 ounces).
2. End results:
a. The rancher produces 18 ounces of meat and trades 5 ounces, leaving him with 13
ounces of meat. He also grows 12 ounces of potatoes and receives 15 ounces in the
trade, leaving him with 27 ounces of potatoes.
Figure 2
page-pf5
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 37
II. Comparative Advantage: The Driving Force of Specialization
A. Absolute Advantage
B. Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantage
1. Definition of opportunity cost: whatever must be given up to obtain some item.
a. For the rancher, it takes ten minutes to produce one ounce of potatoes. Those same ten
minutes could be used to produce one-half ounce of meat. Thus, the opportunity cost of
producing an ounce of potatoes is one-half ounce of meat.
Prove to your students that it would take each of them more than eight hours to
produce these quantities on their own.
Table 1
page-pf6
38 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
2. Definition of comparative advantage: the ability to produce a good at a lower
opportunity cost than another producer.
3. Because the opportunity cost of producing one good is the inverse of the opportunity cost of
producing the other, it is impossible for a person to have a comparative advantage in the
production of both goods.
C. Comparative Advantage and Trade
1. When specialization in a good occurs (assuming there is a comparative advantage), total
output will grow.
2. As long as the opportunity cost of producing the goods differs across the two individuals,
both can gain from specialization and trade.
D. The Price of the Trade
1. For both parties to gain from trade, the price at which they trade must lie between the
opportunity costs.
Hannah Montana, “Mascot Love.
(Season 4, 4:05-5:04.) While unclogging
the sink, Robby (the father) realizes he is late for a meeting. When he decides to hire
a plumber, his son Jackson volunteers to fix the sink for $50. The father agrees, and
he admits he would have paid more. This is a nice short clip for showing comparative
advantage. After the clip, discuss both Robby’s and Jackson’s opportunity costs.
Your students may have a hard time comprehending this. Make sure that you go
through these calculations several times and write out every step on the board.
page-pf7
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 39
E. FYI: The Legacy of Adam Smith and David Ricardo
1. In Adam Smith's 1776 book
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,
he writes of the ability of producers to benefit through specialization and trade.
IV. Applications of Comparative Advantage
A. Should Tom Brady Mow His Own Lawn?
1. Imagine that Brady can mow his lawn faster than anyone else can.
Activity 1Creating Comparative Advantage Examples
Type : In-Class Assignment
Topics: Specialization, interdependence, self-interest, comparative advantage
Materials needed: 3-5 candy bars (or similar items to use as prizes)
Time: 15 minutes (first day), depends on number of groups (second day)
Class limitations: works in any size class
Purpose
This assignment allows students to further explore comparative advantage.
Instructions
Divide the class into groups of three or four to write a comparative advantage problem of
their own. Tell them to make creative, humorous, yet plausible examples.
page-pf8
40 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
4. It is likely that someone else would have a lower opportunity cost of mowing Brady’s lawn;
this individual would have a comparative advantage.
5. Both he and the person hired will be better off as long as he pays the individual more than
the individual's opportunity cost and less than $20,000.
B. Should the United States Trade with Other Countries?
1. Just as individuals can benefit from specialization and trade, so can the populations of
different countries.
2. Definition of imports: goods produced abroad and sold domestically.
C.
In the News: The Changing Face of International Trade
1. Technology is rapidly changing the goods and services that are traded across international
borders.
SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS:
Quick Quizzes
1. Figure 1 shows Robinson Crusoe’s production possibilities frontier for gathering coconuts and
catching fish. If Crusoe lives by himself, this frontier limits his consumption of coconuts and
Discuss how differences in resource endowments can be significant factors in
determining opportunity cost and comparative advantage. Such differences include
climate, soil composition, education and training of the labor force, capital stock, and
infrastructure.
page-pf9
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 41
2. Crusoe’s opportunity cost of catching one fish is 10 coconuts, since he can gather 10
coconuts in the same amount of time it takes to catch one fish. Friday’s opportunity cost of
3. If the world’s fastest typist happens to be trained in brain surgery, she should hire a
secretary because the secretary will give up less for each hour spent typing. Although the
brain surgeon has an absolute advantage in typing, the secretary has a comparative
advantage in typing because the secretary would have a lower opportunity cost of typing.
Questions for Review
1. The production possibilities frontier will be linear if the opportunity cost of producing a good
2. Absolute advantage reflects a comparison of the productivity of one person, firm, or nation to
that of another, while comparative advantage is based on the relative opportunity costs of
3. Many examples are possible. Suppose, for example, that Roger can prepare a meal of hot
dogs and macaroni in just 10 minutes, while it takes Anita 20 minutes. Also suppose that
page-pfa
42 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
4. Comparative advantage is more important for trade than absolute advantage. In the example
6. A nation will export goods for which it has a comparative advantage because it has a smaller
opportunity cost of producing those goods. As a result, citizens of all nations are able to
consume quantities of goods that are outside their production possibilities frontiers.
Problems and Applications
1. a. See Figure 2. If Maria spends all 5 hours studying economics, she can read 100 pages, so
that is the vertical intercept of the production possibilities frontier. If she spends all 5
hours studying sociology, she can read 250 pages, so that is the horizontal intercept. The
opportunity costs are constant, so the production possibilities frontier is a straight line.
b. It takes Maria 2 hours to read 100 pages of sociology. In that time, she could read 40
pages of economics. So the opportunity cost of 100 pages of sociology is 40 pages of
economics.
page-pfb
2. a.
Workers needed to make:
One Car
One Ton of Grain
U.S.
1/4
1/10
Japan
1/4
1/5
c. Because a U.S. worker produces either 4 cars or 10 tons of grain, the opportunity cost of
one car is 2 1/2 tons of grain, which is 10/4. Because a Japanese worker produces either
4 cars or 5 tons of grain, the opportunity cost of one car is 1 1/4 tons of grain, which is
5/4. Similarly, the U.S. opportunity cost of a ton of grain is 2/5 car (4 divided by 10) and
the Japanese opportunity cost of a ton of grain is 4/5 car. This results in the following
table:
Opportunity Cost of:
One Car (in terms of tons
One Ton of Grain (in
page-pfc
44 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
d. Neither country has an absolute advantage in producing cars, because they are equally
productive (the same output per worker); the United States has an absolute advantage
in producing grain, because it is more productive (greater output per worker).
g. From any situation with no trade, in which each country is producing some cars and
some grain, suppose the United States changed one worker from producing cars to
producing grain. That worker would produce 4 fewer cars and 10 additional tons of grain.
Then suppose the United States offers to trade 7 tons of grain to Japan for 4 cars. The
United States will do this because it values 4 cars at 10 tons of grain, so it will be better
off if the trade goes through. Suppose Japan changes one worker from producing grain
to producing cars. That worker would produce 4 more cars and 5 fewer tons of grain.
Japan will take the trade because it values 4 cars at 5 tons of grain, so it will be better
off. With the trade and the change of one worker in both the United States and Japan,
each country gets the same amount of cars as before and both get additional tons of
grain (3 for the United States and 2 for Japan). Thus, by trading and changing their
production, both countries are better off.
b. Because Pat has a comparative advantage in making pizza, she will make pizza and
exchange it for root beer that Kris makes.
page-pfd
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 45
b. See Figure 4. If all 10 million workers produce 2 cars each, they produce a total of 20
million cars, which is the vertical intercept of the production possibilities frontier. If all 10
million workers produce 30 bushels of wheat each, they produce a total of 300 million
c. If the United States buys 10 million cars from Canada and Canada continues to consume
10 million cars, then Canada will need to produce a total of 20 million cars. So Canada
will be producing at the vertical intercept of the production possibilities frontier.
However, if Canada gets 20 bushels of wheat per car, it will be able to consume 200
million bushels of wheat, along with the 10 million cars. This is shown as point B in the
figure. Canada should accept the deal because it gets the same number of cars and 50
million more bushes of wheat.
5. a. English workers have an absolute advantage over Scottish workers in producing scones,
because English workers produce more scones per hour (50 vs. 40). Scottish workers
have an absolute advantage over English workers in producing sweaters, because
Scottish workers produce more sweaters per hour (2 vs. 1). Comparative advantage runs
the same way. English workers, who have an opportunity cost of 1/50 sweater per scone
page-pfe
46 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
c. Even if a Scottish worker produced just one sweater per hour, the countries would still
gain from trade, because Scotland would still have a comparative advantage in producing
sweaters. Its opportunity cost for sweaters would be higher than before (40 scones per
sweater, instead of 20 scones per sweater before). But there are still gains from trade
because England has a higher opportunity cost (50 scones per sweater).
6. a. With no trade, 1 pair of white socks trades for 1 pair of red socks in Boston, because
productivity is the same for the two types of socks. The price in Chicago is 2 pairs of red
socks per 1 pair of white socks.
c. If they trade socks, Boston will produce white socks for export, because it has the
comparative advantage in white socks, while Chicago produces red socks for export,
which is Chicago's comparative advantage.
page-pff
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 47
7. a. The production possibilities frontiers for the two countries are shown in Figure 5. If,
without trade, a U.S. worker spends half of his time producing each good, the United
States will have 50 shirts and 10 computers. If, without trade, a worker in China spends
half of his time producing each good, China will have 50 shirts and 5 computers.
b. For the United States, the opportunity cost of 1 computer is 5 shirts, while the
opportunity cost of a shirt is 1/5 computer. For China, the opportunity cost of 1 computer
is 10 shirts, while the opportunity cost of 1 shirt is 1/10 computer. Therefore, the United
States has a comparative advantage in the production of computers and China has a
comparative advantage in the production of shirts.
c. The price of a computer would fall between 5 and 10 shirts. If the price was below 5, the
United States would not be willing to export computers because the opportunity cost of a
shirt for the United States is 1/5 computer. If the price was greater than 10 shirts, China
would not be willing to import computers because (for China) the opportunity cost of a
computer is 10 shirts.
page-pf10
48 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
8. a. An average worker in Brazil has an absolute advantage in the production of coffee
because he requires less time than an average worker in Peru.
b. An average worker in Peru has a comparative advantage in the production of coffee.
The opportunity cost of each ounce of coffee for the average worker in Peru (1.5 ounces
of soybeans) is lower than the opportunity cost of each ounce of coffee for the average
worker in Brazil (3 ounces of soybeans).
9. a. True; two countries can achieve gains from trade even if one of the countries has an
absolute advantage in the production of all goods. All that is necessary is that each
country have a comparative advantage in some good.
d. False; to be good for both parties, the trade price must lie between the two opportunity
costs.
e. False; trade that makes the country better off can harm certain individuals in the
country. For example, suppose a country has a comparative advantage in producing
wheat and a comparative disadvantage in producing cars. Exporting wheat and importing
cars will benefit the nation as a whole, as it will be able to consume more of both goods.
However, the introduction of trade will likely be harmful to domestic auto workers and
manufacturers.
page-pf11
Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 49
11. a. Hillary has an absolute advantage in the production of both goods because she is able to produce
more in the same amount of time.
c. See Figure 6. If Bill and Hillary spend all of their time producing food, they can produce 30 units
[(10 1) + (10 2)] per day. If they spend all of their time producing clothing, they can produce
40 units per day [(10 1) + (10 3)].
Figure 7
page-pf12
50 Chapter 3/Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
of food for each unit of clothing produced). If they choose to produce only clothing, they can
produce 40 units of clothing. See Figure 8.

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.