978-1337127363 Chapter 2 Solution Manual

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 9
subject Words 2388
subject Authors Christopher M. Snyder, Walter Nicholson

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
page-pf1
The problems in this chapter are primarily mathematical. They are intended to give students
some practice with the concepts introduced in Chapter 2, but the problems in themselves offer
few economic insights. Consequently, no commentary is provided. Results from some of the
analytical problems are used in later chapters, however, and in those cases the student will be
directed back to this chapter.
Solutions
2.1
22
( , ) 4 3 .f x y x y
6 2 3
dx
d. The
( , ) 16f x y
contour line is an ellipse centered at the origin. The slope of the
line at any point is given by
Notice that this slope becomes
more negative as x increases and y decreases.
2.2 a. Profits are given by
2
2 40 100.R C q q
The maximum value is found
by setting the derivative equal to 0:
4 40 0
d = q +
dq

,
implies
*10q
and
*100.
CHAPTER 2:
Mathematics for Microeconomics
page-pf2
2.4 Setting up the Lagrangian,
(0.25 ).x y xy
L
The first-order conditions are
1,
x
y

L
*40 .tg
b. Substituting for
*,t
2
*40 40 800
*
2
( ) 800.
df t
dg g

page-pf3
page-pf4
Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics
2
*
.MC
By the fundamental theorem of calculus,
0
( ) ( ) (0),
q
MC x dx TC q TC
page-pf5
180.5 98
82.5.


d. Assuming profit maximization, we have
2
2
( ) ( )
( 1)
( 1) ( 1) 98
2
( 1) 98.
2
p pq TC q
p
p p p
p





e. i. Using the above equation,
( 20) ( 15) 82.5 0 82.5.pp

ii. The envelope theorem states that
*( ).d dp q p
That is, the derivative of
the profit function yields this firm’s supply function. Integrating over
p
shows
the change in profits by the fundamental theorem of calculus:
20
15
20
15
20
2
15
(20) (15)
( 1)
2
180 97.5
82.5.
p
p
ddp
dp
p dp
pp






Analytical Problems
2.9 Concave and quasi-concave functions
The proof is most easily accomplished through the use of the matrix algebra of quadratic forms.
See, for example, Mas Colell et al.,1995, pp. 937939. Intuitively, because concave functions lie
below any tangent plane, their level curves must also be convex. But the converse is not true.
Quasi-concave functions may exhibit “increasing returns to scale”; even though their level
curves are convex, they may rise above the tangent plane when all variables are increased
together.
page-pf6
Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics
2
A counter example would be the CobbDouglas function, which is always quasi-
concave, but convex when
1.


2.10 The CobbDouglas function
a.
1
2 1 2
2
11 1 1
2
22 1 2
11
12 21
1
12
0,
( 1) 0,
( 1) 0,
0.
0,
f x x
f x x
fx
x
x
f
fx
x
fx










Clearly, all the terms in Equation 2.114 are negative.
b. A contour line is found by setting the function equal to a constant:
12
,y c x x


implying
1
21
.x c x
Hence,
2
1
0.
dx
dx
2.11 The power function
is concave. Because
12
, 0,ff
Equation 2.114 is also satisfied, so the function is
quasi-concave.
c.
y
is quasi-concave as is
.y
However,
y
is not concave for
1.

This can be
shown most easily by
1 2 1 2
(2 ,2 ) 2 ( , ).f x x f x x

2.12 Proof of envelope theorem
Formatted: Indent: Left: 0", First line: 0"
page-pf7
Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics
2
a. The Lagrangian for this problem is
b., c. Multiplication of each first-order condition by the appropriate deriviative yields
2211
1 2 1 2 0.
dx dx dx dx
f f g g
da da da da



*12
12 .
a
da
dx dx
d
df f f f
da a
e. Differentiation of the constraint
12
( ), ( ), 0g x a x a a
yields
1
2
dx dx
dg g g g
*.
a a a
df fg
da
L
Lagrangian shows also that
*.
dA
dP
This shows that the Lagrange multiplier does indeed show this incremental gain in
this problem.
2.13 Taylor approximations
a. A function in one variable is concave if
( ) 0.fx

Using the quadratic Taylor
page-pf8
page-pf9
1
11
x

4. To show Markov’s inequality use
21 ()
Ex

f. 1. Show that the PDF integrates to 1:
2
223
11
81
1.
3 9 9 9
x
x
xx
dx




2
234
11
15 5
( ) .
3 12 12 4
x
x
xx
E x dx

( 1 0Px
):
0
023
11
1.
3 9 9
x
x
xx
dx


page-pfa
Chapter 2: Mathematics for Microeconomics
2
2
22
2 2 2
22
Var( ) ( )
2 ( ) [ ( )]
()
.
2[ ( )] [ ( )]
( ) [ ( )]
x E x E x
E x xE x E x
E x E x E x
E x E x




b. Here, we let
x
yx

and apply Markov’s inequality to
y
and remember that
x
can only take on positive values.
2
2
22
22
()
( ) ( ) .
x
Ey
P y k P y k kk
page-pfb
independent.
page-pfc

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.