978-0134519579 Chapter 21

subject Type Homework Help
subject Authors Marc J Melitz, Maurice Obstfeld, Paul R Krugman

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
Chapter 21
Optimum Currency Areas
and the Euro
Chapter Organization
How the European Single Currency Evolved.
What Has Driven European Monetary Cooperation?
Box: Brexit.
The European Monetary System, 19791998.
Germany Monetary Dominance and the Credibility Theory of the EMS.
Market Integration Initiatives.
European Economic and Monetary Union.
The Euro and Economic Policy in the Euro Zone.
The Maastricht Convergence Criteria and the Stability and Growth Pact.
The European Central Bank and the Eurosystem.
The Revised Exchange Rate Mechanism.
The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas.
Economic Integration and the Benefits of a Fixed Exchange Rate Area: The GG Schedule.
Economic Integration and the Costs of a Fixed Exchange Rate Area: The LL Schedule.
The Decision to Join a Currency Area: Putting the GG and LL Schedules Together.
What Is an Optimum Currency Area?
Other Important Considerations.
Case Study: Is Europe an Optimum Currency Area?
The Euro Crisis and the Future of EMU.
Origins of the Crisis.
Self-Fulfilling Government Default and the “Doom Loop.
A Broader Crisis and Policy Responses.
162 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
ECB Outright Monetary Transactions.
The Future of EMU.
Summary
Chapter Overview
The establishment of a common European currency and the debate over its possible benefits and costs was
one of the key economic topics of the 1990s. Students should be familiar with the euro but probably not
with its technical aspects or its history. This chapter provides them with the historical and institutional
background needed to understand this issue. It also introduces the idea of an optimum currency area and
presents an analytical framework for understanding this concept.
The discussion in this chapter points out that European monetary integration has been an ongoing process.
Fixed exchange rates in Europe were a by-product of the Bretton Woods system. When strains began to
appear in the Bretton Woods system, concerns arose about the effects of widely fluctuating exchange rates
between European countries. The 1971 Werner Report called for the eventual goal of fixed exchange rates
in Europe. Reasons for this included enhancing Europe’s role in the world monetary system, declining
confidence that the United States would place its international monetary responsibilities ahead of national
interests, and turning the European Union into a truly unified market. Also, many Europeans hoped
economic unification would encourage political unification and prevent a repeat of Europe’s war-torn
history.
The first attempt at a post-Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system in Europe was the “Snake.” This
effort was limited in its membership and placed too high a burden of adjustment on countries with weak
currencies. The European Monetary System (EMS), established in 1979, was more successful. The
original member countries of the EMS included Germany, France, Italy, Belgium, Denmark, Luxembourg,
the Netherlands, and Ireland. In later years, the roll of membership grew to include Spain, Great Britain,
and Portugal. The EMS fixed exchange rates around a central parity. Most currencies were allowed to
fluctuate above or below their central rate by 2.5%, although the original band for the Italian lira and the
bands for the Spanish peseta and the Portuguese escudo allowed for fluctuations of 6% in either direction
from the central parity.
After attacks and realignments in its early years, the EMS grew to become sturdier than its predecessors.
The presence of small bands instead of pure fixed rates helped, as did the guarantee of credit from strong
to weak currency countries. The EMS was, in some sense, simply a peg to the DM. Many felt that the
dominant position of the DM had allowed other countries to import Germany’s inflation fighting
credibility and that this was another advantage of fixed rates in Europe.
Chapter 21 Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro 163
A key component of the EMS was the presence of capital controls. However, limits on capital mobility
were counter to a unified European market. Starting in 1987, capital controls were gradually phased out.
The removal of these controls contributed to the EMS crisis of 19921993. German reunification had led
to higher interest rates in Germany (to fight inflationary pressures), but other countries were not in a
position to follow the rate hikes. Fierce attacks followed, and some countries (the United Kingdom and
Italy) left the EMS in 1992, and the bands were widened to 15% in August 1993.
In 1986, the European Union launched a more aggressive integration package known as “1992” that was
intended to complete the internal market by 1992. To further that goal, a plan of the European Economic
and Monetary Union, which involved a single currency and was embodied in the Maastricht Treaty, was
begun, and by 1993 had been accepted by all EU countries. Reasons for pursuing a single currency
included furthering market integration, broadening the viewpoint of monetary policy by moving decision
making from the Bundesbank to a European Central Bank, avoiding the difficulties in maintaining fixed
rates with free capital movements, and supporting political unification.
A crucial aspect of EMU has been the goal of economic convergence embodied in the Maastricht
convergence criteria and the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). These agreements stipulate low deficits and
debt-to-GDP ratios and are an attempt by low-inflation countries to prevent free-spending counterparts
from turning the euro into a weak currency. Eleven nations participated in the launch of the euro in 1999,
with the United Kingdom and Denmark choosing not to join, Sweden failing the exchange rate stability
criteria, and Greece failing all criteria (Greece joined two years later). The nations in the euro area have
ceded monetary control to the Eurosystem, comprised of the European Central Bank (ECB) plus the 18 (at
press!) national central banks of the euro area. The national central banks are now part of an overarching
structure headed by the governing council of the ECB. The ECB is a very independent central bank with
no political control and little accountability. In addition, a new exchange rate mechanism has begun in
which non-euro EU members peg to the euro.
There are both advantages and drawbacks to this decision to form a common currency union. The theory
of optimum currency areas provides a way to frame an analysis of the benefits and costs of a single
currency. The benefits of a common currency are the monetary efficiency gains realized when trade and
payments are not subject to devaluation risk. These benefits rise with an increase in the amount of trade or
factor flows, that is, with the extent of economic integration. A common currency also forces countries to
give up their independence with regards to monetary policy (at least those countries that are not at the
“center” of the system). This may lead to greater macroeconomic instability, although the instability is
reduced the more integrated the country is with the other members of the common currency area. The
analyses of the benefits and costs of membership in a common currency area are presented in the text
164 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
chapter as the GG and LL schedules, respectively. The GG-LL framework is applied to the question of
whether Europe is an optimum currency area.
An illuminating way to frame the question is to compare the United States to Europe. The evidence that
Europe is an optimum currency area is much weaker than the evidence supporting the notion that the
United States is an optimum currency area. Trade among regions in the United States is much higher than
trade among European countries. Labor is much more mobile within the United States than within Europe.
This is significant as capital mobility has increased, suggesting that a country hit with a negative economic
shock may actually experience worse unemployment given that capital will flow to other countries, while
labor does not. Furthermore, federal transfers and changes in federal tax payments provide a much bigger
cushion to region-specific shocks in the United States than do analogous EC revenues and expenditures,
which have no clear mechanism for fiscal federalism. Finally, there are greater differences in factor
endowments in Europe, which may promote greater regional specialization to take advantage of
economies of scale. Such regional specialization increases the possibility of asymmetric shocks that a
common monetary policy has difficulty dealing with.
The chapter then considers the future of the EMU. The facts that the European Union is probably not an
optimum currency area, that economic union is so far in front of political union, that EU labor markets are
very rigid, and that the SGP constrains fiscal policies will all present challenges to Europe’s economy and
to its policy makers in the years ahead. Additional challenges will be faced with the likely eastward
expansion of the EMU, given the larger structural differences between current EMU members and the
Central and Eastern European candidates that joined the European Union in 2004. In addition, the
increased popularity of economic nationalism motivated by anti-immigrant fears that drove the Brexit vote
presents an obstacle to further economic integration. Instructors may wish to call upon current events and
news stories that illuminate how these challenges are being met.
Such a current event to consider is the euro zone debt crisis that originated in Greece in 2010. Budget
deficits and debts in Greece were revealed to be much higher than had been reported, leading to a large
selloff of Greek assets. Borrowing costs rose not only in Greece, but in fellow euro zone members Ireland,
Italy, Portugal, and Spain as investors worried that the debt crisis would rapidly spread. The roots of this
crisis extended back even further, however, to a (later revealed to be false) sense of confidence in the debt
of these euro zone countries on the periphery. The interest rate spreads between these nations and the most
credit worthy countries using the euro (e.g., Germany) narrowed, injecting capital into these countries.
Borrowing and spending rose dramatically, leading to large current account deficits in these periphery
nations. Thus, when the financial crisis began, many of these nations were already deeply in debt.
A swift bailout by the strong currency EMU members could have resolved the crisis, but countries like
Chapter 21 Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro 165
Germany did not want to pay the bill for excessive government spending by other nations. A combined
bailout between the EMU and the IMF was eventually reached, but the plan was met with significant
opposition, highlighting one of the difficulties in managing the currency union. Emerging from this crisis
was recognition of the need to further coordinate fiscal policy across the Eurozone. The Fiscal Stability
Treaty signed in 2013 by 16 countries attempts to achieve this goal.
Answers to Textbook Problems
1. The stability of the EMS depended upon the ability of member countries’ central banks to defend
their currencies. The level of foreign currency reserves to which a central bank has access affects its
2. The maximum change in the lira/DM exchange rate was 4.5% (if, for example, the lira starts out at
the top of its band and then moves to the bottom of its band). If there was no risk of realignment, the
3. A 3% difference on the annual rate of a five-year bond implied a difference over five years of
4. The answers to the previous two questions are based upon the relationship between interest rates and
exchange rates implied by interest parity because this condition links the returns on assets
166 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
5. A favorable shift in demand for a country’s goods appreciates that country’s real exchange rate. A
favorable shift in the world demand for non-Norwegian EMU exports appreciates the euro (and hence the
6. Compare two countries that are identical except that one has larger and more frequent unexpected shifts in
its money-demand function. In the DD-AA diagrams for each country, the one with the more unstable
7. a. While in the ERM, British monetary authorities were obliged to maintain nominal interest rates at a level
commensurate with keeping the pound in the currency band. If this obligation were removed, British
c. British policy makers may have gained credibility as being strongly committed to fight inflation and to
d. A high level of British interest rates relative to German interest rates would suggest high future inflation
in Britain relative to that in Germany by the Fisher relationship. Higher British interest rates may also
Chapter 21 Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro 167
e. British interest rates may have been higher than German interest rates if British output were relatively
higher. The smaller gap at the time of the writing of the article cited may reflect relatively poor British
8. Each central bank would have benefited from issuing currency because it would have gained seigniorage
revenues when it printed money; that is, it could have traded money for goods and services. Money
9. A single labor market would facilitate the response of member countries to country-specific shocks.
Suppose there is a fall in the demand for French goods that results in higher unemployment in France. If
10. a. The table below compares the average rates of inflation, unemployment, and real GDP growth in the
United Kingdom and the euro zone from 19982015 using data from the World Bank.
Inflation
Unemployment
Real GDP Growth
The United Kingdom has had a stronger economy for much of the period since 1998 as compared to
b. The chart below gives the central bank interest rates for both the UK and the euro zone between 1999
168 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
Had the United Kingdom been part of the euro area, it would have shared monetary policy with the
other countries. On the one hand, this would have meant interest rates were perhaps too low for the
11. When the euro appreciated against China’s currency in 2007, EU countries that compete with China
in third country export markets should have seen a larger drop in aggregate demand as various
customers may have switched to the suddenly relatively cheaper Chinese products. Germany should
12. Much like the concern that individual country governments would borrow too much and put pressure
on the ECB to print too much money, an excessive CA deficit of an individual country may signal
Chapter 21 Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro 169
13. All of these countries experienced significant increases in their current account balances (though the
14. If a country had an “escape clause” and could readily leave the Eurozone, the currency stability
offered by a monetary union is weakened. If the ECB signals that it will no longer act as a lender of
15. A condition of the bailout package to Cyprus was that some bank deposits in Cypriot banks would
essentially be taxed to help pay for the financial support. To make this tax binding, the government
16. a. A fiscal expansion in Germany would shift the euro area DD curve to the right. If this is a
permanent fiscal expansion, then the change in the expected exchange rate will also shift the AA
curve down, reflecting the asset market clearing at an appreciated value of the euro. In the end, output
170 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.