978-0134519579 Chapter 19

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 9
subject Words 1747
subject Authors Marc J Melitz, Maurice Obstfeld, Paul R Krugman

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
page-pf1
Chapter 19
International Monetary Systems:
An Historical Overview
Chapter Organization
Macroeconomic Policy Goals in an Open Economy.
Internal Balance: Full Employment and Price Level Stability.
External Balance: The Optimal Level of the Current Account.
Box: Can a Country Borrow Forever? The Case of New Zealand.
Classifying Monetary Systems: The Open-Economy Monetary Trilemma.
International Macroeconomic Policy under the Gold Standard, 18701914.
Origins of the Gold Standard.
External Balance under the Gold Standard.
The Price-Specie-Flow Mechanism.
The Gold Standard “Rules of the Game”: Myth and Reality.
Internal Balance under the Gold Standard.
Case Study: The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Regimes:
Conflict over America’s Monetary Standard during the 1890s.
The Interwar Years, 19181939.
The Fleeting Return to Gold.
International Economic Disintegration.
Case Study: The International Gold Standard and the Great Depression.
The Bretton Woods System and the International Monetary Fund.
Goals and Structure of the IMF.
Convertibility and the Expansion of Private Capital Flows.
Speculative Capital Flows and Crises.
Analyzing Policy Options for Reaching Internal and External Balance.
Maintaining Internal Balance.
page-pf2
142 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
Maintaining External Balance.
Expenditure-Changing and Expenditure-Switching Policies.
The External Balance Problem of the United States under Bretton Woods.
Case Study: The End of Bretton Woods, Worldwide Inflation, and the Transition to Floating Rates.
The Mechanics of Imported Inflation.
Assessment.
The Case for Floating Exchange Rates.
Monetary Policy Autonomy.
Symmetry.
Exchange Rates as Automatic Stabilizers.
Exchange Rates and External Balance.
Case Study: The First Years of Floating Rates, 19731990.
Macroeconomic Interdependence under a Floating Rate.
Case Study: Transformation and Crisis in the World Economy.
Case Study: The Dangers of Deflation.
What Has Been Learned Since 1973?
Monetary Policy Autonomy.
Symmetry.
The Exchange Rate as an Automatic Stabilizer.
External Balance.
The Problem of Policy Coordination.
Are Fixed Exchange Rates Even an Option for Most Countries?
Summary
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 19: International Policy Coordination Failures
Chapter Overview
This is the first of four international monetary policy chapters. These chapters complement the preceding
theory chapters in several ways. They provide the historical and institutional background students require
to place their theoretical knowledge in a useful context. The chapters also allow students, through study of
historical and current events, to sharpen their grasp of the theoretical models and to develop the intuition
those models can provide. (Application of the theory to events of current interest will hopefully motivate
students to return to earlier chapters and master points that may have been missed on the first pass.)
page-pf3
Chapter 19 International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview 143
Chapter 19 chronicles the evolution of the international monetary system from the gold standard of 1870
1914, through the interwar years, the post-World War II Bretton Woods regime that ended in March 1973,
and the system of managed floating exchange rates that have prevailed since. The central focus of the
chapter is the manner in which each system addressed, or failed to address, the requirements of internal
and external balance for its participants. A country is in internal balance when its resources are fully
employed and there is price level stability. External balance implies an optimal time path of the current
account subject to its being balanced over the long run. Other factors have been important in the definition
of external balance at various times, and these are discussed in the text. The basic definition of external
balance as an appropriate current-account level, however, seems to capture a goal that most policy makers
share regardless of the particular circumstances.
Underlying each of these exchange rate systems is the “open economy trilemma,” the observation that you
can have two, but never three, of the following: exchange rate stability, independent monetary policy, and
free capital mobility. Whereas the gold standard traded independent monetary policy for exchange rate
stability and capital mobility, the Bretton Woods system allowed for autonomous monetary policy by
limiting capital flows, and the modern floating era sacrifices exchange rate stability for the other two
goals. The price-specie-flow mechanism described by David Hume shows how the gold standard could
ensure convergence to external balance. You may want to present the following model of the price-specie-
flow mechanism. This model is based upon three equations:
1. The balance sheet of the central bank. At the most simple level, this is just gold holdings equals the
money supply: G = M.
2. The quantity theory. With velocity and output assumed constant and both normalized to 1, this yields
the simple equation M = P.
3. A balance of payments equation where the current account is a function of the real exchange rate
and there are no private capital flows: CA = f(E × P*/P).
These equations can be combined in a figure like the one below. The 45° line represents the quantity
theory, and the vertical line is the price level where the real exchange rate results in a balanced current
account. The economy moves along the 45° line back toward the equilibrium point 0 whenever it is out of
equilibrium. For example, the loss of four-fifths of a country’s gold would put that country at point a with
lower prices and a lower money supply. The resulting real exchange-rate depreciation causes a current
account surplus, which restores money balances as the country proceeds up the 45° line from a to 0.
page-pf4
144 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
Figure 19-1
The automatic adjustment process described by the price-specie-flow mechanism is expedited by
following “rules of the game” under which governments contract the domestic source components of their
monetary bases when gold reserves are falling (corresponding to a current-account deficit) and expand
when gold reserves are rising (the surplus case).
In practice, there was little incentive for countries with expanding gold reserves to follow the “rules of the
game.” This increased the contractionary burden shouldered by countries with persistent current account
deficits. The gold standard also subjugated internal balance to the demands of external balance. Research
suggests price level stability and high employment were attained less consistently under the gold standard
than in the post-1945 period.
The interwar years were marked by severe economic instability. The monetization of war debt and of
International Monetary Fund was set up to oversee the system and facilitate its functioning by lending to
countries with temporary balance of payments problems.
A formal discussion of internal and external balance introduces the concepts of expenditure-switching and
expenditure-changing policies. The Bretton Woods system, with its emphasis on infrequent adjustment of
fixed parities, restricted the use of expenditure-switching policies. Increases in U.S. monetary growth to
Chapter 19 International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview 145
© 2018 Pearson Education, Inc.
finance fiscal expenditures after the mid-1960s led to a loss of confidence in the dollar and the termination
of the dollar’s convertibility into gold. The analysis presented in the text demonstrates how the Bretton
Woods system forced countries to “import” inflation from the United States and shows that the breakdown
of the system occurred when countries were no longer willing to accept this burden.
Following the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system, many countries moved toward floating exchange
rates. In theory, floating exchange rates have four key advantages: They allow for independent monetary
policy; they are symmetric in terms of the costs of adjustment faced by deficit and surplus countries; they
act as automatic stabilizers that mitigate the effects of economic shocks; and they help maintain external
balance through stabilizing speculation that depreciates the currency of a country with a large current-
account deficit.
These advantages must be matched with the experience of countries running floating exchange rate
regimes. Floating exchange rates should give countries greater autonomy over monetary policy. However,
the evidence suggests that changes in monetary policy in one country do get transmitted across borders,
limiting autonomy. Second, exchange rates have become less stable. For example, in the mid 1970s, the
United States chose to pursue monetary expansion to fight a recession, whereas Germany and Japan
contracted their money supplies to counter inflation. As a result, the dollar sharply depreciated against
these currencies. The symmetry benefit of floating rates is also limited by the fact that the dollar still
serves as the world’s reserve currency, much as it did under Bretton Woods. Although floating rates do
work as automatic stabilizers, the effects may be unevenly distributed within countries. For example, the
U.S. fiscal expansion of the 1980s appreciated the dollar, limiting inflation overall. However, U.S. farmers
were hurt by this action as the stronger dollar weakened exports. With immobile factors of production,
these asymmetric effects can have long-run consequences. Finally, empirical evidence suggests that
external imbalances have actually increased since the adoption of floating exchange rates. The chapter
concludes with a discussion of policy coordination under floating exchange rates. For example, a large
country with a current-account deficit that attempts to reduce its imbalance could cause global deflation.
There is also a market failure at work here in that policies by one country have external effects. For
example, the 20072009 financial crisis sparked a number of fiscal expansions in countries. Increased
government spending in the United States, for example, helped lift demand not just in the United States
but in other countries as well. Because the benefits of fiscal expansion are not fully internalized (though
the costs are through accumulated budget deficits), there will be an inefficiently small expansion from a
global perspective. Thus, international policy coordination, even in a world of flexible exchange rates,
may still be warranted. This is especially relevant given the observation that given increased capital
mobility, fixed exchange rates may not even be an option for most countries in a world without
page-pf6
146 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
international coordination of monetary policy.
Answers to Textbook Problems
1. a. Because it takes considerable investment to develop uranium mines, you would want a larger
current-account deficit to allow your country to finance some of the investment with foreign
savings.
2. Because the marginal propensity to consume out of income is less than 1, a transfer of income from B
to A increases savings in A and decreases savings in B. Therefore, A has a current account surplus and
3. Changes in parities reflected both initial misalignments and balance of payments crises. Attempts to
return to the parities of the prewar period after the war ignored the changes in underlying economic
4. A monetary contraction, under the gold standard, will lead to an increase in the gold holdings of the
contracting country’s central bank if other countries do not pursue a similar policy. All countries
page-pf7
© 2018 Pearson Education, Inc.
5. The increase in domestic prices makes home exports less attractive and causes a current account
6. An increase in the world interest rate leads to a fall in a central bank’s holdings of foreign reserves as
domestic residents trade in their cash for foreign bonds. This leads to a decline in the home country’s
7. Capital account restrictions insulate the domestic interest rate from the world interest rate. Monetary
8. We are given that the growth rate in GDP may be computed as g = (GDPt + 1 GDPt)/GDPt. Solving
for GDP in time t + 1 yields: GDPt + 1 = GDPt(1 + g). Using this expression alongside that derived
for IIPt + 1 allows us to compute:
9. a. We know that China has a very large current-account surplus, placing them high above the XX
line. They also have moderate inflationary pressures (described as “gathering” in the question,
implying they are not yet very strong). This suggests that China is above the II line but not too far
page-pf8
148 Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz International Economics: Theory & Policy, Eleventh Edition
b. China needs to appreciate the exchange rate to move down on the graph toward the balance.
10. The increase in foreign prices will shift the DD curve out to the right as demand for home products
page-pf9
page-pfa
page-pfb
Chapter 19 International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview 151
1974
10.5
11.0
0.5
1975
5.8
9.1
3.1
1976
5.1
5.7
0.6
15. If other central banks sell dollars for euros, then it is equivalent to a sterilized sale of dollars because
neither the United States nor any other central bank’s asset side of the balance sheet has changed.
16. Students may find navigating the Australian Bureau of Statistics website challenging, given the large
volume of information available on this site. That said, once the data has been collected, the solution
to this problem is fairly straightforward.

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.