978-0132992282 Chapter 13 Solution Manual Part 2

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 17
subject Words 3812
subject Authors Andrew B. Abel, Ben Bernanke, Dean Croushore

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
page-pf1
Figure 13.17
Foreign IncomeThe effect of an increase in foreign income on the IEB curve is just the opposite of the
effect of an increase in domestic income. Suppose that before the increase in foreign income the current and
future real exchange rates are represented by point E on IEB1 in Figure 13.18. Because foreign consumers are
made wealthier by the increase in income, they will buy more of the goods produced by the home country
in the current period and in the future, which increases net exports by the home country in both periods. An
appreciation of the current real exchange rate, represented by the movement to point F, will reduce the net
exports of the home country and restore external balance. Alternatively, an appreciation of the future real
exchange rate, represented by the movement to point H, would restore external balance. Therefore the new
IEB curve, IEB2, which passes through points F and H, lies above the original IEB curve, IEB1.
Figure 13.18
Shifts in Demand A shift in demand away from foreign goods toward goods produced by the home
country shifts the IEB curve upward, just as an increase in foreign income does. The reason is that, like an
increase in foreign income, a shift in demand toward domestic goods increases both current and future net
exports by the home country. For external balance to be restored, the current real exchange rate or the
future real exchange rate must appreciate; so the IEB curve shifts upward.
page-pf3
1.94 euros per dollar (1.94 is 97% of 2.00). Converting $10,000 to euros at an exchange rate of 2 euros
per dollar yields 20,000 euros (step 1 in Table 13.2), which are used to buy a German bond. At a 6%
nominal interest rate the German bond earns 1200 euros interest and is worth 21,200 euros at the end
of one year (step 2). Finally, converting 21,200 euros to dollars at 1.94 euros per dollar yields $10,928
(step 3)—which is higher than the $10,800 that would be obtained from investing in a U.S. bond! Thus
page-pf4
1 unit of enom units of
home currency foreign currency
(1 iFor)enom units of foreign
currency [(1 iFor)enom]/
nom
f
e
units
of home currency
Interest Rate Parity
In our example the gross nominal rate of return expected on the German government bond exceeded the
gross nominal rate of return on the U.S. government bond. However, if both types of government bonds
have the same risk and liquidity, this difference in rates of return would not persist for long. If savers are
free to choose between German bonds and U.S. bonds, they will choose the German bonds as long as they
offer a higher gross nominal rate of return than U.S. bonds. But if investors choose German bonds in
preference to U.S. bonds, the rate of return on German bonds will fall and the rate of return on U.S. bonds
will increase until the two rates of return are equal.
In general, when the international asset market is in equilibrium, the gross nominal rates of return to
domestic and foreign assets of comparable risk and liquidity must be the same. This equilibrium
condition can be written as
nom nom
( / )
f
e e
(1 iFor) 1 i, (13.9)
where the left side is the gross nominal rate of return on the foreign bond (Eq. 13.7) and the right side is
the gross nominal rate of return on the domestic bond. The equilibrium condition in Eq. (13.9) is the
nominal interest rate parity condition, which says that the nominal returns on foreign and domestic
financial investments with equal risk and liquidity, when measured in a common currency, must be the
same. [With the approximation in Eq. (13.8) the nominal interest rate parity condition can also be
expressed more simply as iFor enom/enom i. According to this approximate formula for interest rate
parity, the difference between nominal interest rates in two countries equals the rate at which the currency
of the country with the higher nominal interest rate is expected to depreciate.]
Interest rate parity can also be expressed in terms of real interest rates and real exchange rates as the real
interest rate parity condition:
(e/ef)(1 rFor) 1 r, (13.10)
where rFor is the foreign real interest rate, r is the domestic real interest rate, and e and ef are the current
and future real exchange rates. The real interest rate parity condition, Eq. (13.10), is identical to the
nominal interest parity condition, Eq. (13.9), except that the nominal interest and exchange rates in
page-pfb
1.94 euros per dollar (1.94 is 97% of 2.00). Converting $10,000 to euros at an exchange rate of 2 euros
per dollar yields 20,000 euros (step 1 in Table 13.2), which are used to buy a German bond. At a 6%
nominal interest rate the German bond earns 1200 euros interest and is worth 21,200 euros at the end
of one year (step 2). Finally, converting 21,200 euros to dollars at 1.94 euros per dollar yields $10,928
(step 3)—which is higher than the $10,800 that would be obtained from investing in a U.S. bond! Thus
1 unit of enom units of
home currency foreign currency
(1 iFor)enom units of foreign
currency [(1 iFor)enom]/
nom
f
e
units
of home currency
Interest Rate Parity
In our example the gross nominal rate of return expected on the German government bond exceeded the
gross nominal rate of return on the U.S. government bond. However, if both types of government bonds
have the same risk and liquidity, this difference in rates of return would not persist for long. If savers are
free to choose between German bonds and U.S. bonds, they will choose the German bonds as long as they
offer a higher gross nominal rate of return than U.S. bonds. But if investors choose German bonds in
preference to U.S. bonds, the rate of return on German bonds will fall and the rate of return on U.S. bonds
will increase until the two rates of return are equal.
In general, when the international asset market is in equilibrium, the gross nominal rates of return to
domestic and foreign assets of comparable risk and liquidity must be the same. This equilibrium
condition can be written as
nom nom
( / )
f
e e
(1 iFor) 1 i, (13.9)
where the left side is the gross nominal rate of return on the foreign bond (Eq. 13.7) and the right side is
the gross nominal rate of return on the domestic bond. The equilibrium condition in Eq. (13.9) is the
nominal interest rate parity condition, which says that the nominal returns on foreign and domestic
financial investments with equal risk and liquidity, when measured in a common currency, must be the
same. [With the approximation in Eq. (13.8) the nominal interest rate parity condition can also be
expressed more simply as iFor enom/enom i. According to this approximate formula for interest rate
parity, the difference between nominal interest rates in two countries equals the rate at which the currency
of the country with the higher nominal interest rate is expected to depreciate.]
Interest rate parity can also be expressed in terms of real interest rates and real exchange rates as the real
interest rate parity condition:
(e/ef)(1 rFor) 1 r, (13.10)
where rFor is the foreign real interest rate, r is the domestic real interest rate, and e and ef are the current
and future real exchange rates. The real interest rate parity condition, Eq. (13.10), is identical to the
nominal interest parity condition, Eq. (13.9), except that the nominal interest and exchange rates in

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.