978-0132146654 Chapter 5 Lecture Notes

subject Type Homework Help
subject Pages 4
subject Words 1378
subject Authors Marc Melitz, Maurice Obstfeld, Paul R. Krugman

Unlock document.

This document is partially blurred.
Unlock all pages and 1 million more documents.
Get Access
18  Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz •   International Economics: Theory & Policy, Ninth Edition
Chapter 5
Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
.1 Chapter Organization
Model of a Two-Factor Economy
  Prices and Production
  Choosing the Mix of Inputs
  Factor Prices and Goods Prices
  Resources and Output
Effects of International Trade Between Two-Factor Economies
  Relative Prices and the Pattern of Trade
  Trade and the Distribution of Income
Case Study: North–South Trade and Income Inequality
  Factor Price Equalization
Empirical Evidence on the Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Trade in Goods as a Substitute for Trade in Factors
Patterns of Exports Between Developed and Developing Countries
Implications of the Tests
Summary
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 5: Factor Prices, Goods Prices, and Production Decisions
  Choice of Technique
  Goods Prices and Factor Prices
More on Resources and Output
.2 Chapter Overview
In Chapter 3, trade between nations was motivated by differences internationally in the relative productivity
of workers when producing a range of products. In Chapter 4, the Specific Factors model considered
additional factors of production, but only labor was mobile between sectors. In Chapter 5, this analysis
goes a step further by introducing the Heckscher-Ohlin theory.
The Heckscher-Ohlin theory considers the pattern of production and trade which will arise when countries
have different endowments of such factors of production as labor, capital, and land; where these factors are
mobile between sectors in the long run. The basic point is that countries tend to export goods that are
© 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley
19  Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz •   International Economics: Theory & Policy, Ninth Edition
intensive in the factors with which they are abundantly supplied. Trade has strong effects on the relative
earnings of resources, and according to theory, leads to equalization across countries of factor prices.
These theoretical results and related empirical findings are presented in this chapter.
© 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley
Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model     20
The chapter begins by developing a general equilibrium model of an economy with two goods which are
each produced using two factors according to fixed coefficient production functions. The assumption of
fixed coefficient production functions provides an unambiguous ranking of goods in terms of factor
intensities. (A more realistic model allowing for substitution between factors of production is presented
later in the chapter with the same conclusions.) Two important results are derived using this model. The
first is known as the Rybczynski effect. Increasing the relative supply of one factor, holding relative goods
prices constant, leads to a biased expansion of production possibilities favoring the relative supply of the
good which uses that factor intensively.
The second key result is known as the Stolper-Samuelson effect. Increasing the relative price of a good,
holding factor supplies constant, increases the return to the factor used intensively in the production of
that good by more than the price increase, while lowering the return to the other factor. This result has
important income distribution implications.
It can be quite instructive to think of the effects of demographic/labor force changes on the supply of
different products. For example, how might the pattern of production during the productive years of the
“Baby Boom” generation differ from the pattern of production for post–Baby Boom generations? What
does this imply for returns to factors and relative price behavior? What effect would a more restrictive
immigration policy have on the pattern of production and trade for the United States?
The central message concerning trade patterns of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory is that countries tend to export
goods whose production is intensive in factors with which they are relatively abundantly endowed. Comparing
the United States and Mexico, for example, we observe a relative abundance of capital in the United States and
a relative abundance of labor in Mexico. Thus, goods that intensively use capital in production should be
cheaper to produce in the United States and those intensively using labor should be cheaper to produce in
Mexico. With trade, the United States should export capital-intensive goods like computers, while Mexico
should export labor-intensive goods like textiles. With integrated markets, international trade should lead
to a convergence of goods prices. Thus, the prices of capital-intensive goods in the United States and
labor-intensive goods in Mexico will rise. According to the Stolper-Samuelson effect, owners of a
country’s abundant factors (e.g., capital owners in the United States, labor in Mexico) will gain from trade,
while owners of the country’s scarce factors (labor in the United States, capital in Mexico) will lose from
trade. The extension of this result is the Factor Price Equalization theorem, which states that trade in goods
(and thus price equalization of goods) will lead to an equalization of factor prices. These income
distribution effects are more or less permanent, given that factor abundances do not quickly change within
a country. While theoretically, the gains from trade could be redistributed such that everyone is better off,
such a plan is difficult to implement in practice. The political implications of factor price equalization
should be interesting to students.
© 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley
21  Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz •   International Economics: Theory & Policy, Ninth Edition
After presenting the basic theory behind the Heckscher-Ohlin theory, the rest of the chapter examines empirical
tests of the model, beginning with a case study looking at income inequality in the United States Wages paid
to skilled workers in the United States have been rising at a much faster rate than those paid to unskilled
workers over the past few decades. At the same time, there has been a large increase in international trade.
Given that the United States is relatively abundant in skilled labor, the Heckscher-Ohlin theory would
predict that increased trade should lead to higher wages for skilled workers and lower wages for unskilled
workers. On the surface, this appears to be an empirical confirmation of the theory. However, other studies
argue that rising wage inequality can only partially be explained by increased trade. According to the
Heckscher-Ohlin model, the increase in skilled wages should be driven by an increase in the price of skill
intensive goods following trade. However, skill intensive goods prices have not increased by nearly the
same proportion as skilled wages. If rising wage inequality in a rich country like the United States is
driven by factor price equalization, then we should also observe a narrowing gap in developing countries
that are exporting low-skill intensive goods. However, income inequality in these nations is actually larger
than in rich countries. Finally, trade between rich and poor nations is simply not large enough to be entirely
responsible for the size of the income gap. Rather, the increasing skill premium is most likely due to
skill-biased technical innovations like computers that have increased the productivities of skilled workers
more than unskilled workers.
Another empirical observation testing validity of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory is the Leontief paradox. This
is the observation that the capital intensity of U.S. exports is actually lower than that of U.S. imports, exactly
the opposite of what the theory would predict for a capital abundant country. Further evidence of this paradox
is found in global data, with a country’s factor abundance doing a relatively poor job of predicting its trade
patterns. Finally, the theory predicts a much larger volume of trade (given observed differences in factor
endowments) than we actually see in the data. A country like China, for example, has a significant abundance
in labor. However, China’s net exports of labor-intensive goods are lower than what the theory would predict.
Similarly, U.S. net imports of labor-intensive goods are lower than what would be expected given its relative
labor scarcity. An explanation for this “missing trade” is that the assumption of identical technology across
countries is flawed. Rather, there are significant differences in productivity across countries. That said, when
the sample is restricted to trade between developed and developing countries (i.e., North–South trade), the
Heckscher-Ohlin theory fits well (e.g., the United States imports more low-skill products from Bangladesh
and more high-skill products from Germany). This observation has motivated many economists to consider
motives for trade between nations that are not exclusively based on differences across countries. These
concepts will be explored in later chapters. Despite these shortcomings, important and relevant results
concerning income distribution are obtained from the Heckscher-Ohlin theory.
© 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley

Trusted by Thousands of
Students

Here are what students say about us.

Copyright ©2022 All rights reserved. | CoursePaper is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.